Butterfield 1
Murder Rates and the Death Penalty: A Post-Moratorium Era
Brian Butterfield
University of Akron
Department of Economics
Senior Project
Spring 2020
Butterfield 2
Acknowledgement
I would like to thank the entire Economics department for what I have learned during my
collegiate career. To specifically mention Dr. Renna, without whose dedication I would not have
made it through this senior research project. Additionally, Dr. Erickson’s constant feedback on
drafts helped keep me motivated. In an unprecedented time to be a graduating senior, her
telephone advice gave me the confidence to cross the finish line.
Thank you.
Butterfield 3
Abstract:
This paper intends to build upon the limited research in recent years that has
been conducted on the criminal significance of the death penalty. I pose to determine if
there is a significant deterrent effect of murder through the use of the death penalty in the
United States in a moratorium era. Given the controversy of the results of past studies, I
find that higher execution rates have a slight impact in raising the US murder rates. A 1
percent increase in execution rates increases murder rates by a slim 0.01 percent via
OLS. With using the panel data in a one-way fixed effects, the significance strengthens to
a 0.082 percent increase in murders for every 1 percent increase in executions.
Butterfield 4
Table of Contents
I. Introduction 5
II. Survey of Literature 8
III. Theoretical Model Development 11
IV. Model Specification and Results 14
V. Results Interpretation 17
VI. Conclusion 19
VII. References 22
VIII. Appendix 24
IX. SAS Code 27
Butterfield 5
I. Introduction
The Death Penalty Information Center reports that more than 165 individuals wrongly
accused of violent crimes have been executed in the United States since 1973. This does not
include others who had claimed their innocence. The death penalty is as controversial as gun
rights and abortion laws; even before the signing of the Declaration of Independence, there were
arguments for and against capital punishment in the colonies. As of 2020, the American divide is
greater than ever, with 30 states using the death penalty as legal recourse.
Much of the debate stems from the standpoint of morality. Supporters believe capital
punishment is a fitting penalty for the severity of the crime, and taxpayers should not be required
to support a murderer’s life sentence in prison. In contrast, opponents often object on the basis of
moral and religious principle. Some support the death penalty because they believe it prevents
crimes from being commmitted, while others disagree.
Butterfield 6
Figure 1: The comparison of murder rates between death penalty states and non-death penalty states (per 100,000 residents), per the
1
Death Penalty Information Center
According to the Death Penalty Information Center, (Figure 1) over the past 28 years,
states with the death penalty have a higher murder rate per 100,000 residents on average
compared to states that do not have capital punishment. The motivation for the research is not to
determine if there is a significant statistical connection nor a correlation between murder rates
and executions, although there is in fact a conflict in that research itself. The purpose is to
determine if there is a deterrent, and to what effect
. The economic motivation is twofold.
1
https://deathpenaltyinfo.org/facts-and-research/murder-rates/murder-rate-of-death-penalty-states-compar
ed-to-non-death-penalty-states
Butterfield 7
It is important to note that from an economic perspective, the marginal benefits and
marginal costs are the most meaningful when studying allocative efficiency. The additional
benefits of the death penalty are those associated with life imprisonment. That is, the marginal
benefits are the difference between the total benefits of the death penalty and the total benefits of
life imprisonment. Many analyses produce monetary estimates of the cost to put one to death.
However, these studies produce total cost estimates, not marginal cost estimates. From an
economic perspective, society should only use capital punishment if the marginal benefits
outweigh the marginal costs. In the course of analyzing the economic efficiency of capital
punishment, and before providing any recommendations, both the benefits and costs of the death
penalty must be evaluated. Many innocent men die on death row, further creating rifts between
races and classes. The second economic motivation is to reduce murder in the United States,
where murder always negatively affects the economy and welfare of a society. Although this
study does not look at costs versus benefits of the death penalty specifically, it can lead to a
conversation about the viability of the punishment with more data given.
Capital punishment is again a highly debated topic in the United States because of the
moratorium of the death penalty. In a newfound era of controversy of the death penalty, with an
additional ten states at the turn of the century at least considered its moratorium, (Dezhbakhsh)
new evidence is needed on the effectivity of the punishment. Further study into the
post-moratorium states can help strengthen or weaken both sides of the arguments.
The Research Question
Butterfield 8
The aim of this study is to analyze the effectiveness of the death penalty as a murder
deterrent in a post-moratorium era in the United States, and whether it has changed from earlier
periods.
II. Survey of Literature
The fundamental basis of the link between crime and economics is derived from Gary
Becker’s economic theory of crime (1968). The theoretical framework applies simple economic
principles of consumer behavior in a market in which people choose to commit crimes. Becker
established that crime is committed on the basis of rationality, cost to benefit analysis of the
potential offender, and utility maximization. However, this analysis only pertains to rational
decision makers that commit a non-violent crime. Many studies used Becker’s theory to expand
on situations in which the perpetrator commits a violent crime, with assault, rape, and murders
being the forefront area of study. As a result, this original theory lead to the breakdown analysis
of murder versus capital punishment.
Building upon Becker’s original theory, numerous econometric studies have been
conducted to examine the effect of the death penalty as a murder deterrent. Most of the studies
use time series and panel data to measure the effect. Isaac Ehrlich’s (1975) research was one of
the original pioneering studies on whether execution rates cause a decrease in murder rates in the
United States. By extending Becker’s theory of the rational offender, Ehrlich developed a
positive approach towards testing the deterrence hypothesis using multiple regression techniques.
The study used U.S. aggregate time series data over a 35 year period as its structure, and
suggested a significant deterrent effect, sharply contrasting with earlier findings. Critics of
Butterfield 9
Ehrlich later addressed the issue of his findings: the proper functional form of the relationship
between the murder rate and its determinants. It is claimed that evidence of a deterrent effect is
found within the logarithmic form but not with the linear form, and therefore Ehrlich’s results
depended entirely on his choice of functional form.
Ehrlich inspired an interest in econometric analysis of deterrence, leading to many studies
that used his data, but included different regressors or different choices of endogenous vs.
exogenous variables. As a consequence, economists have argued against the viability of
researching the death penalty’s implication on homicide rates. Katz (2003) argued that the
quality of life in prison is likely to have a greater impact on criminal behavior than the death
penalty. Using state-level panel data covering the period 1950-1990, he demonstrated that the
death rate among prisoners (due to prison conditions) is negatively correlated with crime rates,
consistent with deterrence, and with robust findings. Furthermore, it was found that there is little
systematic evidence that the execution rate influenced crime rates in that time period.
Dezhbakhsh (2003) focused on post-moratorium panel data of the effect of the death
penalty as a murder deterrent. They examined the deterrent hypothesis using county-level,
post-moratorium panel data and a system of simultaneous equations. The procedure employed
overcame common aggregation problems using panel data from 1977-1996. It eliminated the
bias arising from unobserved heterogeneity, and provided evidence relevant for current
conditions, such as the current crime situation in the model. As a result, the findings suggested
that capital punishment has a strong deterrent effect, similiar to Ehrlich’s findings.
Introducing a panel study of United States state-level data over a twenty year period,
Zimmerman (2004) also estimated the deterrent effect of capital punishment. Specifically in this
Butterfield 10
paper, Zimmerman’s attention to detail addresses Ehrlich’s problem of endogeneity bias from the
non-random assignment of death penalty laws in each state and a relationship between murders
and the deterrence probabilities. The estimation results suggest that structural estimates of the
deterrent effect of capital punishment are likely to be downward biased due to the influence of
simultaneity. By correcting for simultaneity bias, the findings resulted in a stronger deterrent
effect. The results suggest that the announcement effect of capital punishment, (if potential
murders do actually witness an execution in proximity to the time in which they plan on
committing their offense) as opposed to the existence of a death penalty provision is the
mechanism actually driving the deterrent effect associated with state executions. Zimmerman
used the ordinary least squares method, along with fixed effects and two-stage least squares
regression analysis to come to this conclusion.
Finally, in a comprehensive survey of literature from 1973-2009, Nagin (2012) building
upon this earlier research, used panel data once more to determine whether the death penalty has
a deterrent effect on homicide, and if so, the size of this effect. The data includes all 50 states,
and the time periods covered are from the late 1970s through the late 1990s. Over this time
period, there have been variations in the frequency of death penalty sentences, executions, and
the legal availability of the death penalty. With these types of data, the strategy for identifying an
effect of the death penalty on homicides has been, roughly speaking, to compare the variation
over time in the average homicide rates among states that changed their death penalty sanctions
versus those that did not. No connection was established between these measures and the
perceived sanction risks, being caught, sentenced, and executed, of potential murderers. Neither
Butterfield 11
the fixed effects multiple regression models that were tested nor the proposed instruments in the
study were able to identify causation between capital punishment and murder rates.
This research will include updated annual data in the United States that has not been seen
in past literature. By studying a recent time period where additional states have imposed a
moratorium, the intent is to determine if the econometric findings are consistent with past
findings, or whether they yield different results. In addition, to differentiate from past literature
new variables will be added to test whether the effect of the execution rate is modified by these
factors. Like Dezhbakhsh and Zimmerman, for this research simultaneity must also be addressed
in order to yield more accurate results. I hypothesize the inclusion of new variables that account
for socio-demograpic differences will strengthen the murder deterrent theory from previous
authors.
III. Theoretical Development
The basis of theoretical development is derived from Becker’s theory of crime (1968).
The theory, looking at an criminal’s likelihood to commit a crime as a rational individual that
makes their decision based on a “risk versus reward” approach is seen in figure 2:
Butterfield 12
Figure 2: Becker’s Theory of Crime
2
Becker explains with the increase of the total number of offenses, the marginal cost in
committing a crime increases, while the marginal revenue for the individual decreases. F
and P
represent the cost of punishment and the probability of conviction, respectively.
It has been noted that most individuals who commit murder do not adhere to rational
decision making; yet it can be expanded to most murders under the assumption that there is
always a risk-reward approach to a perpetrator’s actions. As a result, including all murders in a
population is not inappropriate. By expanding on Becker’s theory of crime, Daniel Nagin (2012)
furthered development research on the topic by creating the following model:
RDR f(Z ) X M
it
= α
i
+ β
it
+ γ
it
+ δ
it
+ ε
it
2
https://link.springer.com/referenceworkentry/10.1007%2F978-1-4614-7883-6_17-1
Butterfield 13
The model shows that the murder rate ( ) is homicides per 100,000 residents inRDR M
it
state i
in year t
. is an expected cost function of committing a capital homicide that depends(Z )f
it
on the vector of death penalty or other sanction variables with the parameter measuring Z
it
γ
the effect of the death penalty on homicide rate. Importantly, this effect is assumed to be
homogenous across states i
and year t
.
This study applied certain economic and social modifications to examine how execution
rates affect the murder rates in the United States. Variables analyzed are first and foremost the
murder rates (per 100,000) in all fifty states, and total annual executions by year in all states.
Additionally, variables included were additional factors that could affect the outcomes, such as
unemployment rates. ( )X δ
it
I will use a panel data method similar to Nagin and Zimmerman. A primary benefit of
panel data is that one observes homicide and execution rates in the 50 states over multiple years.
This allows a researcher to effectively account for unobserved features of the state or of the time
period that might be associated with both the application of the death penalty and the homicide
rate. Some states may have different social norms or ways of thinking that could lead to a bias in
in murder rates or execution rates. The cultures in a progressive California and a more
conservative Texas are somewhat different in this regard.
The panel data accounts for these differences. , which is also referred to as the state α
i
fixed effect, allows the mean homicide rate to vary by state, while is the time fixed effect, β
it
allowing the mean homicide rate to vary over time. Finally, is the random variable that will ε
it
account for all error terms. This accounts for all the unobserved factors that determine the
homicide rate.
Butterfield 14
IV. Model Specification and Results
The empirical model used in this study is designed to examine the execution rate’s effect
on murder rates over the recent years in which some states have imposed a moratorium on the
death penalty. To properly examine the hypothesis, the state level panel data will cover the
periods of 2013-2017 for the 50 states, excluding the District of Columbia. This is to examine the
implications of the death penalty in a post-moratorium era in the country.
The econometric modeling used for the ordinary least squares and fixed effects models is
as follows:
nMU RDER lnExecution Incarcpcnt UnemRate Blackpcnt lnBachelor l
it
= β
0
+ β
1 it
+ β
2 it
+ β
3 it
+ β
4 it
+ β
5 it
+ ε
it
Where:
lnMURDER
is the dependent variable in the empirical model which measures the
murders per 100,000 residents by state by year.
lnExecution
measures all of the prisoners on death row who have been arrested,
convicted, and executed. This does not factor in any prisoners that were wrongly convicted, as
those who were executed innocently are a part of the execution statistics, and those who were let
go are not factored in. This coefficient is expected to have a negative sign since previous
findings either resulted in a negligible effect on the murder rate or a decrease in murder rate.
lnIncarc
measures the logarithm of the incarceration rate of a specific state. As
previously stated, being incarcerated is seen as a marginal cost that one associates with the risk
of committing a crime. If it is proof that incarceration is a deterrent in a rational offender’s
mindset when committing a murder, than a higher population in jail or prison may lead to an
Butterfield 15
offender’s thinking that there is a higher chance that they will not get away with their crimes,
resulting in the potential murderer not going through with the act due to the marginal cost of
them going to prison. This may be a matter of endogeneity however, and must be looked at
carefully. Consequently, the expected coefficient is expected to be negative according to
Becker’s theory of crime.
UnemRate
measures the unemployment rate percentage that comes from the number of
unemployed United States citizens divided by all that are currently in the labor force. According
to Grogger’s (1998) Model of Unemployment and Crime, as the unemployment rate goes up, the
crime rate, both violent and passive, is also expected to increase. This coefficient is expected to
have a positive effect on all of the occasions of murder.
Black
measures the percentage of African Americans in a state. This is an important
variable because it helps measure another aspect of state demographics. Past studies have found
that black males are affected by murder rates higher than white males and females. (Gender was
not included in this study because there are only a few rare exceptions when women have been
sentenced to death in the United States.) It is expected that black
is to have a positive effect on
murder rates, however the interpretation of this variable is complicated and must be taken with a
grain of salt. Zimmerman (2004) noted that race is one of the most controversial aspects of
capital punishment. In a review of numerous studies of the death penalty, the U.S. General
Accounting Office (1990) found that individuals who murdered whites were much more likely to
be sentenced to death than if their victim was non-white. I believe that this information will not
greatly affect the results of the ordinary least squares and fixed effect method, but it could affect
the interpretation of the results.
Butterfield 16
lnBachelor
measures the amount of the state population over 25 that has obtained a
bachelor’s degree. To include an education variable was critical because it measures certain
socio-demographics. Those with degrees have higher access to higher paying jobs which
theoretically incentivizes them to work in legal trades, and are generally more satisfied in their
adult lives. The variable is expected to have a negative impact, since more bachelor’s degrees
will likely result in higher quality of living, resulting in lower murder rates.
Murder rates consist of all three degrees of killing, including premeditated,
non-premeditated, (also known as a crime of passion) and manslaughter. It is important to note
that only premeditated murders are considered for the death penalty. The dependent variable in
the empirical model accounts for the total occurrences of all documented murders, with crime
data and statistics collected from the Bureau of Justice Statistics. It is important to note that these
murder rate statistics do not include all crimes that occur, but are reported and documented. This
aggregate data consists of the compilation of data collected by local law enforcement agencies
and federal law agencies.
To account for socio-demographic and state specific variables, the number of
unemployed citizens in a state, the percentage of the population over 25 with a bachelor degree,
and a proxy for race are added that accounts for a given state’s population of black citizens. All
of these variables are included in the panel data set and were sourced from the US Census
Bureau. The state specific economic variable of interest included in the study is the executions,
which was collected by the Death Penalty Information Center.
An incarceration variable was added as a deterrent variable, since it represents the
likelihood of an offender being caught and convicted. Increased incarceration rates would
Butterfield 17
theoretically have served as an increasing deterrent to commit a crime because it represents the
total marginal cost with committing a crime, rather than only the potential cost of getting caught
by an investigator or the police.
The panel data may not include all of the variables that may account for the variation in
the relationship between execution rates and murder rates since it is impossible to see all of the
variables that affect murder. This is an inherent flaw in ordinary least squares (OLS)
methodology that was originally conducted. To use all of the aspects of the panel data and
control for all of the different states and years, fixed effects were added to the state level data.
Fixed effects, a method used to assist in controlling for omitted variable bias due to unobserved
heterogeneity, are added to attempt to eliminate the variation in murders caused by factors that
vary across states but are still constant over time; also known as year-specific heterogeneity.
V. Results Interpretation
In order to determine if execution rates can affect murder rates both OLS and one-way
fixed effects models were used. In the econometric model, using an F-test to compare the
one-way fixed effect model to the OLS estimators showed that F=98.33 with p=0.0001. A
different and additional method of statistical analysis may have been able to identify a greater
estimation technique, but the results suggest that the model is improved when controlling for a
state fixed effect. I will now discuss the outcomes of the OLS estimation and controlling for the
fixed-effect.
Using OLS, I observed a 0.001 percent increase in murder rates for every 1 percent
increase in executions. However, this result was not statistically significant at a 90 percent level.
Butterfield 18
This finding changed when using the fixed effect method, strengthening to a 0.082 percent
increase in murders with the same increase in executions. The range set by standard deviations
was 0.057. At a 95 percent significance level, this is the most surprising aspect of the fixed effect
model as it relates to the variable of interest in the study. The fixed effect model found execution
rates to have a positive effect on the total rate of murders. This result is not in line with the
economic theory that an increased state execution rate results in a lower average murder rate.
There were also several other statistically significant variables in the first OLS model.
With 95 percent signifance, a one percent increase in unemployment resulted in a 0.04 percent
increase in murder rates in both the OLS and fixed effect models. Using the fixed effect model
compared to the OLS model saw no change in the significance level, with both at 95 percent.
The range set by standard deviation was 0.019. This coefficient is quite low, however, it is in line
with the theoretical framework suggesting that an increase in unemployment will increase the
amount of crime (Becker 1968).
The findings also suggest that for every one percent increase in a state’s incarceration
percentage, murders increased by 0.172 percent at a 95 percent significance level. Although once
again not in accordance with prediction and sentiment, the variable did not prove to be at a 90
percent significance level when tested with the fixed-effect method, which was to be expected
using that model.
Next, for every one percent increase in bachelor’s degrees, murder rates when tested with
the OLS method decreased by 0.088 percent. This proved to be in line with theory as murder
rates decrease with a higher education level. When testing using the fixed effects method, the
variable was found to be insignificant.
Butterfield 19
Finally, for every one percent increase in a state’s black population percentage, murders
increased by 0.031 percent. Originally tested at a 99 percent significance level with OLS, the
variable decreased in significance when tested at fixed-effect, decreasing to a 0.019 percent
increase in murders yet remaining at the 90 percent significance level. The range set by standard
deviation was 0.006. This result is in line with theory and sentiment, but as mentioned in the
variable discussion, it must be taken lightly. Black and white discrimination in the U.S. justice
system has been present for its entire history, and is likely a large determinant factor in guilty
murder convictions.
VI. Conclusion
In an effort to determine the capital punishment rate’s effect on murder rates in the
United States, the study concluded that there is not sufficient evidence that executions have some
impact on reducing murder rates, failing to satisfy my hypothesis. With improved methodology
compared to the OLS modeling, using fixed effects resulted in a 0.082 percent increase in
murders for every one percent increase in executions.
In a post-moratorium era for the death penalty, factoring in the findings, research would
suggest that prohibiting the use of capital punishment would decrease the number of murders. It
can be assumed that the use of capital punishment is near negligible, with figure 1 showing the
number of murders has decreased in the studied years compared to those previous.
In comparison to previous research, the study furthers the inconclusivity of the
homicide-punishment relationship. Dezhbakhsh (2003) found that there was a strong deterrent
effect, while Nagin (2012) and Katz (2003) found that there could be no established connection
Butterfield 20
between the two. When comparing the findings between post-moratorium years and previous
ones in the literature, the inconsistency in results continued.
There are some limitations in researching the effect of capital punishments on homicides
as a whole. The shortcomings in existing research suffer two specific flaws that make them
uninformative about the effect of capital punishment on homicide rates. First, the relevant
question regarding the deterrent effect of the death penalty is the “differential deterrent effect” of
execution compared to the detererrent effect of life imprisonment. Most convicts, regardless of
execution rates by state, are sentenced to life sentences without the possibility of parole and
never face death. None of the studies reviewed account for the severity of non-capital
punishment in their analyses. Second, the absence of the differential deterrent effect points out
the lack of study of how no capital punishment affects a potential murderer. With only the capital
punishment side being included in the studies, it presents a serious flaw of data interpretation in
the entire field of research.
For this study specifically, there were several limitations on my research. It is impossible
to capture all of the economic and intangible variables that could be a determinant of murders, so
there are likely to be several omitted variables that would benefit the model. Identifying these
variables would be beneficial in adding to the model’s explanatory power and a reduction to
omitted variable bias. Variables that could be included in future studies could account for more
socio-demographic issues, such as age groupings, income, and divorce rates. Furthermore,
locating data for more than the five years was troublesome, and more annual data would help
improve this study. Lastly, all of the aforementioned limitations in the field of study, such as
determining the proper homicide-capital punishment lag, made it difficult to analyze the research
Butterfield 21
with confidence even though many variables were statistically significant. If a different variable
could be used, a change in education would be appropriate. Using a high school diploma or an
associate degree variable would serve as a better education variable, since criminals tend to be
less educated (Lochner 2004).
It should be noted with past findings that even if executions are a deterrent to homicides,
it does not mean that capital punishment should be imposed. The sentencing of innocent inmates
to death is one of the many flaws of the United States justice system and its method of capital
punishment. Further measures must be enacted to ensure those uncommon mistakes do not
happen.
Butterfield 22
VII. References
Becker, G. S. 1968. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach
. Journal of Political
Economy 78, 526–536.
Dezhbakhsh, Hashem, Paul H. Rubin, and Joanna Shepherd. 2003. Does capital punishment have
a deterrent effect? New evidence from post-moratorium panel data
. American Law and
Economics Review 5:344–76.
Ehrlich, Isaac. 1975. The deterrent effect of capital punishment: A question of life and death
.
American Economic Review 65:395–417.
Grogger, Jeff. 1998. Market Wages and Youth Crime
. Journal of Labor Economics 16: 756–91.
Glaze, Lauren. “Correctional Populations in the United States, 2013.” Bureau of Justice Statistics
(BJS), 19 Dec. 2014, https://www.bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=pbdetail&iid=5177.
Kaeble, Danielle. “Correctional Populations in the United States, 2014.” Bureau of Justice
Statistics (BJS), 29 Dec. 2015, https://www.bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=pbdetail&iid=5519.
Kaeble, Danielle. “Correctional Populations in the United States, 2015.” Bureau of Justice
Statistics (BJS), 26 Dec. 2016, https://www.bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=pbdetail&iid=5870.
Kaeble, Danielle. “Correctional Populations in the United States, 2016.” Bureau of Justice
Statistics (BJS), 26 Apr. 2018, www.bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=pbdetail&iid=6226.
Katz, Lawrence, Steven D. Levitt, and Ellen Shustorovich. 2003. Prison conditions, capital
punishment, and deterrence
. American Law and Economics Review 5:318–43.
Lochner, and Moretti. “The Effect of Education on Crime: Evidence from Prison Inmates,
Arrests, and Self-Reports.” American Economic Review
, The American Economic
Association, 1 Mar. 2004, www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/000282804322970751.
Butterfield 23
Nagin, Daniel, et al. 2012. Deterence and the Death Penalty
. National Research Council of the
National Academies 4:48-71
U.S. General Accounting Office (1990), “Death Penalty Sentencing: Research Indicates Pattern
of Racial Disparities,” report GAO-GDD-90-57.
Zimmerman, P. R. 2004. State Executions, Deterrence, and the Incidence of Murder
. Journal of
Applied Economics, 7(1), 163–93.
“Population Distribution by Race/Ethnicity.” The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, 4 Dec.
2019, www.kff.org/other/state-indicator/distribution-by-raceethnicity/.
Butterfield 24
VIII. Appendix
Table 1: Variable Definitions
and Sources
Variable
Definition
Source
lnMurder
Murders per 100,000
residents by state by year
Bureau of Justice Statistics
lnBachelor
Bachelor’s degrees per
100,000 residents held by
those 25 years and older
Bureau of Labor Statistics
lnExec
Total executions by year by
state
The Death Penalty
Information Center
UnemRate
Annual average
unemployment rate by state
Bureau of Labor Statistics
blackpcnt
percent of state population
that is black
US Census Bureau
incarcpcnt
percent of state population
that is incarcerated
Bureau of Justice Statistics
Butterfield 25
Table 2: Descriptive Statistics
Variable
N
Mean
Std Dev
Min
Max
Range
Expected
Sign
MurderRate
250
4.525
2.235
0.904
12.424
11.520
Dependent
Variable
UnemRate
250
5.252
1.471
2.400
9.600
7.200
+
BachelorRate
250
33.226
6.148
21.815
50.337
28.522
-
Exec
250
0.585
2.015
0
16.000
16.000
-
blackpcnt
250
9.800
9.112
0.374
36.447
36.073
+
Incarcpcnt
250
1.873
0.737
0.759
6.245
5.486
-
Note: 50 states shown in 5 observed murder years (2013-2017). All of the descriptive statistics
are shown before taking logarithms.
Butterfield 26
Table 3: Murders
Table 3: Murders/Execution
OLS
FE
Dependent Variable
lnMurder
lnMurder
Intercept
***0.7567*** (8.03)
-0.6931 (-0.32)
Unemployment
**0.040** (2.24)
**0.040** (2.09)
lnBachelor
***-0.088*** (-3.05)
-0.093 (-0.68)
lnExec
0.001 (0.10)
**0.082** (1.43)
blackpcnt
***0.031*** (10.16)
*0.019* (3.18)
incarcpcnt
**0.172** (2.31)
0.097 (1.66)
N
250
250
R-Squared
0.5248
0.8682
F-Value
53.89
97.33
Note: t-values are in
parenthesis. *,**, and ***
denote significance at the 90
percent, 95 percent, and 99
percent level, respectively
Butterfield 27
IX. SAS Code
/** Import an XLSX file. **/
PROC IMPORT DATAFILE="/folders/myfolders/SeniorProject/FINALEXCELDRFT2.xlsx"
OUT=WORK.sp2020
DBMS=XLSX
REPLACE;
RUN;
/** Print the results. **/
PROC PRINT DATA=WORK.sp2020; RUN;
proc means data=work.sp2020;
var Population Murder Black Unemployment Bachelor Exec Incarc;
run;
/** adtnlvar = aditional variables included**/
data adtnlvar;
set work.sp2020;
/** Murder Rate is murders per 100,000 state residents**/
/** Bachelor Rate is bachelor Degrees per 100,000 state residents**/
MurderRate = Murder/(Population/100000);
Butterfield 28
BachelorRate = Bachelor/(Population/100000);
lnIncar = log(Incarc);
blackpcnt = ((Black/Population)*100);
Incarcpcnt = ((Incarc/Population)*100);
lnBachelor = log(BachelorRate);
lnMurder = log(MurderRate);
lnincarce = log(Incarcpcnt);
proc means;
var Black Unemployment BachelorRate Exec
Incarc lnMurder lnIncar lnBachelor blackpcnt Incarcpcnt MurderRate;
run;
proc means;
var MurderRate Unemployment BachelorRate Exec blackpcnt Incarcpcnt;
proc reg data=adtnlvar;
model lnMurder = Unemployment lnBachelor Exec blackpcnt lnincarce;
run;
proc reg data=adtnlvar;
model lnMurder = Unemployment lnBachelor blackpcnt lnincarce;
proc sort data=adtnlvar;
by year;
proc panel data=adtnlvar;
title fixed effect murder rates;
Butterfield 29
id state year;
model lnMurder = Unemployment lnBachelor Exec blackpcnt
lnincarce/FIXONE;
run;